Monday 14 December 2020

Colonialism: The Economic Impact (Part 1)


Colonialism led to a substantial outflow of financial resources. It is best documented in the case of British India. The economic historian Angus Maddison concludes that there was "a substantial outflow which lasted for 190 years", and: "If these funds had been invested in India, they could have made a significant contribution to raising income levels."

The so-called “Home Charges”, the official transfers of funds by the colonial government to Britain between 1858 and 1947, consisted mainly of debt service, pensions, India Office expenses in Britain, purchases of military items and railway equipment.


King George with Queen Mary at the Durbar ceremony in Delhi, 1911 © Getty

Debt service occurred not only because of investment in infrastructure, but also due to costly wars and architectural extravagances like the building of New Delhi. Government procurement of civilian goods, armaments and shipping was carried out almost exclusively in the home country; there were no efforts at developing industrial enterprises in India which could have delivered these goods at probably lower prices. Of these official payments, therefore, service charges on non-productive debt, pensions and furlough payments can be considered as a balance of payment drain due to colonialism.

For the 1930s, Maddison estimates these home charges in the range of £40 to £50 million a year. In addition, there were private remittances, probably about £10 million a year, and dividend and interest remittances by shipping and banking interests, plantations, and other British investors.

Diamond (1988) emphasizes the establishment of monopolistic state control of cash crop production and exportation as an important impact of colonialism, as well as the exclusive control over the mining of minerals and the development of infrastructure. Thereby, “it discouraged the development of an indigenous capitalist class by favouring the metropole’s industrial exports and foreign firms, and (…) by curtailing individual access to the land”.

The effect of colonialism on trade is assessed by Mitchener and Weidenmier. They argue that “empires increased trade by lowering transactions costs and by establishing trade policies that promoted trade within empires. In particular, the use of a common language, the establishment of currency unions, the monetizing of recently acquired colonies, preferential trade arrangements, and customs unions help to account for the observed increase in trade associated with empire”. Trade between the colonial power and its colonies was regulated in different ways: with tariff assimilation/customs union, with preferential tariff policies and/or with “open door” policies.

Chase-Dunn sees the impact of colonial trade policy in a shift towards a more “bilateral (colonial) structure”, typically occurring in phases of global economic slow-down and increasing competition.

Fieldhouse discusses long-term change in colonial trade policies, but – with some exceptions – a stronger protectionism of French colonialism compared to British.

Grier supports this argument and suggests for Spanish colonies a strong mercantilist approach. In cases in which industrially manufactured products from the metropole economy were cheaper, as in the case of British textile exports to India, a ‘deindustrialization’ in the colony was the consequence.

Plantations were core elements of the colonial economy. In general, a plantation “is owned by a legal entity or individual with substantial capital resources, the production techniques are based on industrial processing machinery, and the labour force consists of wage laborers resident on the estate”. The development of a plantation economy required expropriation, which took place in different forms, implying displacement of indigenous population. For example, in British-Ceylon (Sri Lanka), the plantation boom of the “coffee era” (1830-1880) was enabled through a combination of a special land-sales policy and financial control through banks and agency houses:

“In 1815 the colonial government assumed ownership of all uncultivated land. In 1844, the price on Crown land was raised high enough that buying was effectively limited to Europeans with enough capital. Since banking was British controlled, the banks perpetuated British policy by making almost all their loans to European planters and export-import-traders and not to Ceylonese peasants. As a result, most export production remained in British hands.”

Plantations were a world different from the surrounding land. Working and living conditions on plantations were in general bad. Many plantation owners used a long-term debt strategy to bind workers to their enterprise. Tropical diseases were widespread and accidents common.

Sugar, tea, sisal, and palm oil were typical plantation products, while wet rice, coffee, rubber, tobacco and cacao were also or mainly produced by small farmers. While in some colonies, governments assisted actively in setting up large estates, in others they favoured small production units. The production of cash crops by peasants need not necessarily to be less exploitive than plantation work. Especially in the case of agricultural monopsonies via marketing boards, traders and/or state officials could gain huge rents by underpaying peasants for their produce.

In the Belgian Congo, the collection of wild rubber on the huge private concessions “resulted in the depopulation of entire villages and the perpetration of heinous crimes against humanity (…). Villages unwilling or unable to meet the assigned daily quotas of production were subject to rape, arson, bodily mutilation and murder” (Nzongola-Ntalaja). The situation was the private domain of King Leopold and in the neighbouring French Congo was similar.

Opening plantations in the interior depended on adequate means of transport and communication to get the produce to the ports. This was a challenge especially in the mountainous areas where coffee and tea were produced.

The main transportation technology in 19th century Europe were railways, and they were built in the colonies as well. These were also instruments of imperial control, because the technology and much of the capital came from the metropole country. Between 1865 and 1914, railway expansion absorbed 42% of British capital exports (Huff 2007). There were purely military and strategic reasons behind certain railway projects, e.g. in British-India the line leading up to the Khyber Pass to Afghanistan or the Mombasa-Uganda railway intended to ensure British claims on eastern Sudan against the progressing French.

Compared with the huge land masses of the Indian peninsula and Central and South Africa, the situation in Southeast Asia (and to a certain degree in West Africa) was different: In the archipelago, the plantations were never far from the coast, and the most of the rice for export was grown in the deltas of the rivers Irrawaddy (Burma) and Mekong (Indochina).

The control of mining was one of the key interests of colonial powers, and large-scale mining had a huge impact on the local population. Migrant wage labour, the need for housing, food and entertainment triggered considerable urbanization, social distortion and the advent of new forms of sociability and political activity. Mining took a heavy toll on the workers, due to accidents, but also because of the unhealthy living conditions which contributed to spreading diseases.

The main arguments regarding the economic impact of colonialism are the ‘drain of wealth’, expropriation (mainly of land), the control over production and trade, the exploitation of natural resources, and the possible improvement of infrastructure.

India’s share of world GDP fell from 27% in 1700 to 3% by 1947 (at the time of independence). But Britain’s share of world GDP increased from about 3% in 1700 to 9% in 1870. Today (2020) Britain has 2.17% of global GDP (in PPP terms) while India’s GDP is 8.27% of global GDP (PPP terms). On a per capita basis the picture is rather different.

What can we learn from this? Colonialism is not a desired outcome. Today we have MNCs doing the same thing in vulnerable, third world nations. The WTO is controlled by large nations, even the U.S. is displeased with it. There must be a social conscience of restoring past indiscretions with positive contribution to the welfare of those who were exploited previously. A sort of repentance and reconciliation. And that starts with an apology. Will the colonizers do that? And truly build a commonwealth of nations!

 

Reference:

1.     The Economic Impact of Colonialism, https://www.worlddevelopment.uzh.ch/

2.     Shashi Tharoor (2017), Inglorious Empire: What the British Did to India

 

No comments:

Post a Comment