Few issues are more contentious, in many
developed and emerging economies, as a government’s budget. Those who argue in
favour of a balanced budget claim growing government debt is harmful to the
future. Others say a government budget isn’t like a household
budget. Deficits are used to ward off economic impact of pandemics or other
extenuating circumstances.
Proponents of balanced budgets also
support restricting power and scope of the government. Opponents want the
government to have the power to effect wide-ranging changes if needed.
Economists are divided on how important
it is to tackle the budget deficit and total outstanding debt. The mainstream
view is that debt isn’t a cause for concern, especially for the United States
(with USD 23 trillion). Proponents of Modern Monetary Theory (“MMT”) argue that
deficits and debts don’t matter because the government, unlike a household, can
simply print more money. This assumes inflation is weak or contained.
Government borrowing becomes a problem only when it raises aggregate demand to
inflationary levels.
Others argue that government debt will
become a problem and it is easier to tackle it now. They further argue that
ever-rising debt will eventually cause investors to question government’s
ability to repay debt, resulting in rising interest rates and quash
private-sector investment. And if interest rates rise too quickly then it may
be difficult to repay debt or service interest. This may lead to difficult
circumstances or higher inflation.
Two American economists Carmen Reinhart
and Kenneth Rogoff (Harvard) published a paper, “Growth in Time of Debt” in
2010. This paper argued that when gross external debt reaches 60% of GDP, a
country’s annual growth will decline by 2%. And where external debt exceeds
90%, GDP growth will be cut in half. Appearing after the Great Recession
(2008), the 90% debt threshold hypothesis provided ammunition for pro-austerity
policies.
In 2013, academic critics accused
Reinhart and Rogoff (R&R) of employing methodology that had errors, which
did not support their conclusions. Further papers by R&R and the IMF did not
have similar errors and reached conclusions equivalent to that of the earlier
paper. However, impact on GDP growth was deemed lower. A consensus amongst
economists on the 90% threshold hypothesis in relation to external debt and
economic growth, nevertheless, remains elusive.
What do some observations suggest?
During the Asian Financial Crisis,
countries with large external debt were vulnerable to currency “attack”.
Indonesia, Thailand and South Korea were notably so, Malaysia imposed capital
controls and was shielded from the attack on the ringgit.
In more recent times, Argentina has
suffered budget deficits, high external debt and currency depreciation/
collapse. That supports R&R hypothesis. The lesson to be learned is perhaps
maintaining a prudent level of external debt, well below the 90% (or 60%) of
GDP level.
Should we then balance the budget?
The British government under Cameron and
May pursued this balanced budget objective. Austerity policies over 8-9 years
caused untold misery and suffering. Now, under the Conservative Party with
Boris, it looks more like Labour policies are in place, partly because of
Covid-19. There is no inherent need to balance the budget. Keynesian economics
will suggest budget deficits are to stimulate a moribund economy. It is when
deficits occur every year for long periods of time that GDP growth begins to
taper off with debt servicing and inflation rising in prominence.
No comments:
Post a Comment